toplogo
Sign In

A Gauss-Seidel Method for Finding Equilibria in Hierarchical Nash Games with Applications to Ride-Hailing Markets


Core Concepts
This paper presents a novel computational approach using a Gauss-Seidel method to find equilibria in hierarchical Nash games, specifically multi-leader-multi-follower games, and demonstrates its effectiveness in a ride-hailing market scenario.
Abstract
  • Bibliographic Information: Franci, B., Fabiani, F., Schmidt, M., & Staudigl, M. (2024). A Gauss-Seidel method for solving multi-leader-multi-follower games. arXiv preprint arXiv:2404.02605v2.

  • Research Objective: This paper aims to develop a computational method for finding equilibria in multi-leader-multi-follower games, a challenging class of hierarchical games with limited existing solutions.

  • Methodology: The authors propose a novel approach that combines tools from mixed-integer optimization and the characterization of variational equilibria using Karush–Kuhn–Tucker conditions. This results in a mixed-integer game formulation, which is then solved using a proximal Gauss–Seidel method with global convergence guarantees for games with a potential structure.

  • Key Findings: The paper demonstrates the effectiveness of the proposed Gauss-Seidel method in solving a novel instance of the ride-hail market problem. The algorithm successfully computes an equilibrium solution, outperforming a naive two-layer approach.

  • Main Conclusions: The proposed Gauss-Seidel method provides an effective and efficient way to find equilibria in multi-leader-multi-follower games, particularly those with a potential structure. The application to the ride-hailing market demonstrates its practical relevance and potential for real-world applications.

  • Significance: This research contributes to the field of game theory and optimization by providing a practical solution for a challenging class of hierarchical games. The application to ride-hailing markets offers valuable insights for platform pricing strategies and driver behavior.

  • Limitations and Future Research: The proposed method relies on the assumption of a potential game structure, which may not hold for all multi-leader-multi-follower games. Future research could explore extending the approach to more general game structures or investigating alternative solution methods for non-potential games.

edit_icon

Customize Summary

edit_icon

Rewrite with AI

edit_icon

Generate Citations

translate_icon

Translate Source

visual_icon

Generate MindMap

visit_icon

Visit Source

Stats
The simulation involved 5 ride-hailing platforms and 10 drivers per platform. Drivers operated in 3 different areas. The maximum service price was set at $32. The minimum wage for drivers was $12. The algorithm achieved convergence in less than 10 iterations for some instances. The average computation time for a best-response strategy was 0.0135 seconds.
Quotes
"Although multi-leader-multi-follower games are a natural model for several applications in engineering systems, to date existence results for equilibria are restricted to special classes of games." "To fill this gap, our main contributions can be summarized as follows: • We develop a global, optimization-based reformulation of the equilibrium conditions for the proposed multi-leader-multi-follower game... • To ensure that the problem is numerically tractable, we recast the leader’s game as a potential game... • We propose a novel formulation for the ride-hail market problem."

Key Insights Distilled From

by Barbara Fran... at arxiv.org 11-12-2024

https://arxiv.org/pdf/2404.02605.pdf
A Gauss-Seidel method for solving multi-leader-multi-follower games

Deeper Inquiries

How could this approach be adapted to handle uncertainties in the ride-hailing market, such as dynamic pricing or fluctuating demand?

This approach could be adapted to handle uncertainties in the ride-hailing market in several ways: Stochastic Optimization: Instead of assuming deterministic parameters, we can incorporate uncertainties like dynamic pricing and fluctuating demand as random variables with probability distributions. This would transform the problem into a Stochastic Multi-Leader-Multi-Follower Game. Techniques like scenario-based optimization or robust optimization can be employed to find solutions that are optimal in expectation or robust to different realizations of uncertainty. Dynamic Game Formulation: To capture the dynamic nature of pricing and demand, the game can be modeled as a Dynamic Game, where players make decisions over time, observing the evolving state of the market. This would require techniques from dynamic programming or reinforcement learning to find equilibrium strategies. Predictive Modeling: Machine learning techniques can be used to predict demand and driver behavior based on historical data and real-time information. These predictions can then be incorporated into the optimization problem, leading to a more accurate representation of the market dynamics. Rolling Horizon Approach: A rolling horizon approach can be implemented where the optimization problem is solved over a finite time horizon, considering the current state and short-term predictions. As new information becomes available, the horizon is rolled forward, and the problem is re-solved. This allows for adaptation to changing market conditions. Feedback Mechanisms: Instead of relying solely on a priori optimization, feedback mechanisms can be introduced to adjust pricing and driver incentives in real-time based on observed market behavior. This can be achieved through dynamic pricing algorithms or by providing drivers with updated information on demand and potential earnings in different areas. By incorporating these adaptations, the proposed approach can be made more robust and applicable to real-world ride-hailing markets characterized by uncertainties and dynamic interactions.

Could the reliance on a potential game structure limit the applicability of this method in real-world scenarios with more complex interactions?

Yes, the reliance on a potential game structure can limit the applicability of this method in real-world scenarios with more complex interactions. Here's why: Restrictive Assumption: The existence of a potential function significantly simplifies the analysis and solution of the game. However, not all games admit a potential function. In real-world ride-hailing markets, interactions between platforms and drivers can be more intricate and may not always align with the conditions required for a potential game. Limited Scope of Interactions: Potential games assume a certain degree of symmetry and alignment in the players' objectives. In reality, ride-hailing platforms often have distinct business models, target audiences, and competitive strategies. These asymmetries can lead to more complex strategic interactions that cannot be easily captured by a potential function. Oversimplification of Dynamics: Real-world ride-hailing markets are characterized by dynamic pricing, network effects, and strategic behavior from both platforms and drivers. Potential games, in their basic form, may not fully capture these dynamic aspects, potentially leading to suboptimal or unrealistic solutions. Addressing the Limitations: While the reliance on potential games can be limiting, there are ways to extend the applicability of the method: Generalized Potential Games: Explore the use of generalized potential games, which relax some of the strict conditions of potential games while still providing some analytical tractability. Decomposition Techniques: Decompose the complex game into smaller, potentially overlapping, sub-games that exhibit a potential structure. These sub-games can then be solved independently or iteratively to find an approximate solution to the original problem. Learning Algorithms: Employ learning algorithms that can adapt to complex and dynamic environments without requiring the explicit knowledge of a potential function. Reinforcement learning, in particular, has shown promise in solving complex games with strategic interactions. By acknowledging the limitations and exploring these extensions, researchers can strive to develop more general and robust methods for analyzing and optimizing ride-hailing markets with realistic complexities.

What are the ethical implications of using algorithms to optimize pricing and driver behavior in ride-hailing markets, and how can these be addressed?

Using algorithms to optimize pricing and driver behavior in ride-hailing markets presents several ethical implications: Algorithmic Bias: Algorithms trained on historical data can inherit and perpetuate existing biases, potentially leading to discriminatory pricing or unfair treatment of certain drivers or riders based on factors like location, demographics, or past behavior. Labor Exploitation: Aggressive optimization focused solely on platform profits can result in exploitative labor practices, such as low wages, long working hours, and lack of benefits for drivers, who often operate as independent contractors. Privacy Concerns: Algorithms often rely on vast amounts of data about riders and drivers, including location data, travel patterns, and personal preferences. This raises concerns about data privacy and the potential for misuse of this information. Market Manipulation: Algorithms can be used to manipulate market dynamics, leading to artificially inflated prices, reduced competition, and decreased consumer choice. Lack of Transparency and Accountability: The decision-making processes of complex algorithms can be opaque, making it difficult to understand how prices are determined or why certain drivers are favored over others. This lack of transparency hinders accountability and can erode trust in the platform. Addressing the Ethical Implications: Fairness and Non-Discrimination: Implement algorithmic fairness constraints to mitigate bias and ensure equitable treatment for all riders and drivers. Regularly audit algorithms for discriminatory outcomes and make necessary adjustments. Driver Welfare: Establish fair labor practices, including minimum wage guarantees, reasonable working hours, and access to benefits for drivers. Consider incorporating driver welfare as an objective in the optimization process, balancing platform profits with driver well-being. Data Privacy and Security: Implement robust data privacy and security measures to protect user information. Obtain informed consent for data collection and usage. Provide users with transparency and control over their data. Market Regulation: Establish regulatory frameworks that promote competition, prevent market manipulation, and ensure fair pricing practices in ride-hailing markets. Transparency and Explainability: Develop algorithms that are transparent and explainable, allowing riders and drivers to understand how decisions are made. Provide clear information about pricing policies and driver incentives. Stakeholder Engagement: Foster open dialogue and collaboration between platforms, drivers, riders, and regulators to address ethical concerns and ensure the responsible development and deployment of algorithms in ride-hailing markets. By proactively addressing these ethical implications, we can strive to create a more equitable, sustainable, and trustworthy ride-hailing ecosystem that benefits all stakeholders.
0
star