toplogo
Войти

Optimal Resource Allocation Using Peer Information in the Absence of Monetary Transfers


Основные понятия
This paper explores the challenge of optimal resource allocation without relying on monetary transfers, focusing on how peer information can be leveraged to design effective allocation mechanisms.
Аннотация

Bibliographic Information:

Niemeyer, A., & Preusser, J. (2024). Optimal Allocation with Peer Information. arXiv preprint arXiv:2410.08954.

Research Objective:

This paper investigates how a principal can optimally allocate a single indivisible good among a set of agents without using monetary transfers, leveraging the information agents possess about each other (peer information). The authors aim to design dominant-strategy incentive-compatible (DIC) mechanisms that incentivize truthful reporting by agents and maximize the principal's utility.

Methodology:

The authors employ a graph-theoretic approach to model and analyze the allocation problem. They introduce the concept of a "feasibility graph" where vertices represent commitments to allocate to an agent under specific type profiles, and edges represent incompatible commitments due to feasibility constraints. This framework allows them to characterize DIC mechanisms as fractional stable sets of the feasibility graph.

Key Findings:

  1. Optimality of Jury Mechanisms in Limited Cases: Jury mechanisms, where designated jurors decide the allocation among candidates without any stake in the outcome, are optimal when there are only two agents or when there are three agents and the good must be allocated.
  2. Prevalence of Stochastic Mechanisms: In most cases, optimal DIC mechanisms involve randomization (stochastic mechanisms). This arises from the need to balance allocating to an agent and utilizing their information. Stochastic mechanisms achieve better outcomes by distributing allocation probabilities around specific cycles (odd holes) in the feasibility graph.
  3. Complexity of Deterministic Mechanisms: Finding an optimal deterministic DIC mechanism is proven to be NP-hard, suggesting a lack of simple, easily interpretable solutions.
  4. Approximate Optimality of Ranking-based Mechanisms: The authors propose a class of "ranking-based mechanisms" that allocate to agents ranked highly by their peers while strategically withholding allocation if dishonest evaluation is suspected. These mechanisms are approximately optimal when agents have limited informational influence (small "informational size").

Main Conclusions:

The study highlights the complexity of optimal allocation without transfers, emphasizing the importance of peer information and the role of stochastic mechanisms. While optimal mechanisms can be intricate, ranking-based mechanisms offer a practical and approximately optimal solution, particularly in environments with many agents and limited individual informational influence.

Significance:

This research contributes to mechanism design theory by analyzing allocation problems with correlated types and without transfers, a setting under-explored in the existing literature. The findings have implications for various real-world scenarios like peer review in academia, resource allocation within organizations, and community-based aid distribution.

Limitations and Future Research:

The paper primarily focuses on allocating a single indivisible good. Future research could explore extensions to multiple goods or divisible resources. Additionally, investigating the performance of ranking-based mechanisms under different network structures and informational settings could provide further insights.

edit_icon

Customize Summary

edit_icon

Rewrite with AI

edit_icon

Generate Citations

translate_icon

Translate Source

visual_icon

Generate MindMap

visit_icon

Visit Source

Статистика
Цитаты

Ключевые выводы из

by Axel Niemeye... в arxiv.org 10-14-2024

https://arxiv.org/pdf/2410.08954.pdf
Optimal Allocation with Peer Information

Дополнительные вопросы

How can the proposed framework be adapted to handle allocation problems with multiple goods or divisible resources?

Adapting the framework to handle multiple goods or divisible resources presents several challenges: 1. Feasibility Graph Complexity: The feasibility graph, a cornerstone of the analysis, becomes significantly more complex. * Multiple Goods: With multiple indivisible goods, the graph needs to represent all possible allocations of the goods, significantly increasing the number of vertices and edges. * Divisible Resources: Representing the allocation of a divisible resource across agents introduces continuity, potentially requiring a move from a graph-based representation to a more general constraint representation. 2. Incentive Compatibility: Dominant-strategy incentive compatibility (DIC) becomes more intricate. Agents may have preferences over different goods or different shares of the divisible resource. Ensuring truthful reporting requires carefully considering how an agent's report affects their allocation across all goods or the entire division of the resource. 3. Characterizing Optimal Mechanisms: The characterization of optimal mechanisms, particularly the role of stochastic mechanisms and extreme points, may not extend directly. The combinatorial structure that leads to the prevalence of stochastic mechanisms in the single-good case might not hold with multiple goods or divisible resources. Possible Adaptations: Multiple Indivisible Goods: One possible approach is to consider a sequential allocation process, where goods are allocated one by one. The feasibility graph could be modified to represent the allocation of a single good at each stage, with the allocation of previous goods influencing the graph structure for subsequent goods. Divisible Resources: Instead of a graph, the feasibility constraints could be represented more generally as a system of inequalities. Techniques from convex optimization might be applicable to analyze the set of feasible and incentive-compatible mechanisms. Key Challenges: Maintaining tractability as the complexity of the problem increases. Finding appropriate generalizations of key concepts like "peer value" and "informational size" to the multi-good or divisible resource setting.

Could there be alternative mechanisms, beyond ranking-based ones, that achieve near-optimality while being conceptually simpler?

While ranking-based mechanisms offer a good balance between simplicity and near-optimality under certain conditions, exploring alternative mechanisms is worthwhile. Here are some potential avenues: 1. Threshold Mechanisms Based on Peer Values: Instead of ranking agents, a simpler mechanism could set a threshold directly on peer values. The principal could allocate the good to a randomly chosen agent whose peer value exceeds the threshold. This mechanism is conceptually simpler than ranking as it avoids the complexity of pairwise comparisons. However, its performance might be more sensitive to the distribution of peer values. 2. Iterative Mechanisms with Limited Communication: Mechanisms that involve limited rounds of communication between the principal and agents could be explored. For example, the principal could iteratively elicit information from agents about a subset of other agents, refining the allocation based on the received information. Designing such mechanisms to be DIC and near-optimal would be crucial. 3. Mechanisms Exploiting Network Structure (if applicable): If there is an underlying social network, mechanisms could be tailored to exploit its structure. For instance, the principal could select a few agents as "seeds" and then use a diffusion process on the network, where agents nominate neighbors for allocation based on their information. Key Considerations for Alternative Mechanisms: Simplicity: The mechanism should be easy to understand and implement in practice. Incentive Compatibility: Ensuring truthful reporting remains paramount. Robustness: The mechanism's performance should be robust to variations in the distribution of types and values.

How does the concept of "informational size" and its impact on mechanism design translate to other economic contexts beyond resource allocation?

The concept of "informational size," while formulated in the context of resource allocation, has broader implications for mechanism design and economic contexts where information is dispersed: 1. Voting and Collective Decision Making: In voting mechanisms, informational size could capture the influence a single voter has on the outcome. * Small Informational Size: Suggests that individual votes have limited impact, potentially leading to more stable outcomes but also raising concerns about voter apathy. * Large Informational Size: Implies that individual votes can be decisive, potentially leading to strategic voting behavior and instability. 2. Networked Markets and Information Diffusion: In settings with network effects, informational size could quantify how much an individual's information affects the decisions of others. * Small Informational Size: Might slow down the diffusion of information and innovation, as individual actions have limited impact on the network. * Large Informational Size: Could lead to rapid cascades and information spread, with potential for both positive (e.g., faster adoption of beneficial technologies) and negative (e.g., spread of misinformation) consequences. 3. Reputation Systems and Online Platforms: On platforms like eBay or Airbnb, informational size could measure the impact of a single review on a seller's or renter's reputation. * Small Informational Size: Might make it harder for high-quality providers to differentiate themselves, as individual reviews have less weight. * Large Informational Size: Could make reputation systems more susceptible to manipulation, as a few positive or negative reviews can significantly impact a participant's standing. General Implications of Informational Size: Mechanism Design: Understanding informational size is crucial for designing mechanisms that are robust to manipulation and achieve desirable outcomes. Small informational size might necessitate mechanisms that aggregate information more effectively, while large informational size requires safeguards against undue influence. Market Design: Informational size can influence market dynamics, affecting information aggregation, price formation, and the distribution of welfare. Market designers might need to consider interventions to mitigate the negative consequences of large or small informational size.
0
star